Skip to content ↓

3 Questions: James Poterba on making infrastructure pay off

MIT economist sees overlooked value in repairs, upgrades, and user fees to help fund projects.
Press Inquiries

Press Contact:

Abby Abazorius
Phone: 617-253-2709
MIT News Office

Media Download

Jim Poterba
Download Image
Caption: As Congress works on an infrastructure bill, MIT Professor Jim Poterba discusses economic aspects of U.S. infrastructure investment.
Credits: Image: Poterba photo courtesy MIT Department of Economics. Highway image from iStockphoto.

*Terms of Use:

Images for download on the MIT News office website are made available to non-commercial entities, press and the general public under a Creative Commons Attribution Non-Commercial No Derivatives license. You may not alter the images provided, other than to crop them to size. A credit line must be used when reproducing images; if one is not provided below, credit the images to "MIT."

Close
Jim Poterba
Caption:
As Congress works on an infrastructure bill, MIT Professor Jim Poterba discusses economic aspects of U.S. infrastructure investment.
Credits:
Image: Poterba photo courtesy MIT Department of Economics. Highway image from iStockphoto.

With a timeframe resembling that of a construction project, the U.S. Congress is working on an infrastructure bill. How effective could the legislation be? In a new paper, James M. Poterba, the Mitsui Professor of Economics at MIT, and co-author Edward Glaeser, an economist at Harvard University, survey economic aspects of infrastructure investment in the U.S. They advocate for cost-benefit analyses of projects, find that repairing infrastructure often pays off more than new projects, and suggest that infrastructure user fees be considered as a source of financing for projects.

The paper, “Economic Perspectives on Infrastructure Investment,” is being published by the Aspen Institute Economic Strategy Group. Poterba, an expert on taxation and government spending, among other topics, notes that many members of the MIT community, especially civil engineers and urban planners, have crucial expertise on the design and construction of infrastructure projects, but that economists can also make important contributions to the selection and scaling of such projects. MIT News talked with Poterba about his new analysis.

Q: Your paper suggests that infrastructure projects vary widely in value. In a country with many infrastructure needs, how can we systematically establish what our infrastructure priorities should be?

A: The economic touchstone for thinking about the infrastructure gap, and which projects should be undertaken, is a very standard tool: cost-benefit analysis. But it’s easier said than done. The benefits of a new bridge or subway line accrue over decades, so estimating them requires projecting utilization and demand far into the future. There are also important network considerations. In Seattle, where there are few connections between some parts of the city and others, one bridge can be very valuable because it establishes new links among areas, while building a duplicative bridge has less value.

At the same time, costs are hard to forecast, especially in areas where infrastructure has the greatest potential benefit and is the most expensive. Despite these challenges, our best hope for avoiding bridges to nowhere, and understanding the differences among projects, is trying to discipline ourselves with cost-benefit analysis.

Say a piece of a freeway in Los Angeles has seven hours a day of heavy congestion. What are we going to do about it? One approach is to build more lanes. Another approach, from the economics toolkit, could be to implement a user charge, recognizing the costs of congestion at some times of day. That would encourage efficient use of the roadway. Undertaking new and expensive building projects in dense urban areas is not necessarily the only way to reach our objectives.

Finally, cost-benefit analyses suggest the returns on maintaining and upgrading existing infrastructure are often higher than the returns on building new projects. That’s partly because many of our already-built highways and airports are in places where demand is greatest. The political process, unfortunately, is a bit biased in favor of new projects. It’s the ribbon-cutting phenomenon. Elected officials get more favorable media coverage for a new highway or bridge, compared to extending an airport runway. But we should examine costs and benefits of maintenance rebuilding projects if our goal is to spend infrastructure dollars most effectively.

Q: Why is infrastructure so expensive in the U.S.?

A: It’s devilishly difficult to make good systematic comparisons of infrastructure costs across places in the U.S. or across countries. But, particularly for megaprojects in cities, the U.S. is an outlier. Some recent tunnel-centered projects in New York City, such as the Second Avenue Subway and the East Side Access project [bringing the Long Island Railroad to Grand Central Station], are very expensive relative to recent tunneling projects in Paris or London. Several things seem to contribute to the cost differences. One is project design. There are pros and cons to this, but the fact is, the U.S. provides opportunities for a lot of stakeholders to enter the discussion about what’s being built. That can raise costs. There’s some indication that newer interstate highways in the U.S. are “wigglier” than older ones, perhaps because one way to avoid neighborhood disruptions is to wind around them.

Second, the way we procure infrastructure can contribute to higher costs. In New York City, longstanding requirements call for separate bidding of every part of an infrastructure project: The electrical work for the Second Avenue Subway needed to be bid separately from the cement work and from the tunneling. If you renovate your kitchen, you would typically have a contractor give you a bid for everything, and there is a comparative advantage to that approach.

Another problem is delay, which increases costs because the project sponsor must borrow for more years, and because it delays the start of project benefits and any associated revenues. This reduces the benefit-to-cost ratio.

Domestic content legislation, which can mandate the use of high-cost [material] inputs, can raise costs. Implementation of prevailing wage standard laws seems to differ across the U.S., in some cases resulting in quite high wage rates for workers involved in contruction projects.

We can’t point to any one thing and say, “That’s the source.” Also, it is important to recognize that some of the factors that contribute to higher costs also have significant benefits. Think of Robert Moses in New York City, bulldozing neighborhoods to push through the Cross-Bronx Expressway — there are good reasons people pushed back on that experience. But it’s useful to recognize that reducing the community impacts of infrastructure project can come at a cost, and that cost needs to be traded off against the value created.   

Q: This paper contends that user fees can help fund infrastructure more extensively. What is the case for that?

A: One question that comes up all the time with infrastructure projects is: How do we pay for them? Raising taxes, using general revenues, and borrowing to fund the projects are time-honored approaches. User fees, such as tolls on bridges, highways, and tunnels, recoup costs from those who use the infrastructure. Congestion tolls are a great example. A charge in airline tickets to recoup airport building costs is another.

One example of a user charge, to offset highway damage, would be a weight-based vehicle miles traveled tax. Engineering evidence suggests the damage to a highway from a vehicle, in terms of eroding the road surface, is proportional to the fourth power of the axle weight, so that a large commercial truck with few axles imposes a lot more damage than your light-duty vehicle. A user fee accounting for that would provide incentives to avoid very heavy trucks, and would make the operators cover the costs of the road damage they impose, while also raising revenue to contribute to highway maintenance.  

One argument against user fees is that they are effectively a tax on lower-income households — including the use of gasoline taxes to finance highways, since as a share of their income, low-income households spend more on gasoline than higher-income households do. But this argument does not apply to some other types of transportation infrastructure. Consider air travel. People in households with incomes above $150,000 per year fly about six times more each year than people in low-income households do. A user fee on airport use would not be particularly burdensome on low-income households. Similarly, commuter rail in Connecticut consists heavily of people riding into New York City, and about half of the riders have incomes of at least $150,000 a year. Use of commuter rail by low-income households is very low, so those households would not bear much of the burden of a user fee on commuter rail.

So labeling all user fees as regressive is a mistake. Rather, one should examine the facts and circumstances in different cases. Financing infrastructure projects is always a challenge, and charging users should not be taken off the table without careful analysis.

Press Mentions

The Wall Street Journal

A new paper co-authored by Prof. James Poterba finds that not all projects to enhance infrastructure are worth investing in, reports David Harrison for The Wall Street Journal. “If we are going to commit a significant amount of resources to new infrastructure projects or to maintain our existing infrastructure, bringing some discipline to the way we decide what we’re spending on is an important element of this,” says Poterba.

Related Links

Related Topics

Related Articles

More MIT News